Sunday, August 2, 2020
A SIPA Faculty Interview COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY - SIPA Admissions Blog
A SIPA Faculty Interview COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY - SIPA Admissions Blog Eric Verhoogen, an associate professor of international and public affairs and economics, followed a somewhat unorthodox path to SIPA. âAfter college at Harvard, I was a high-school teacher in Los Angeles, and then tried my hand at journalism in Berkeley and at the Nation. Then I was a labor organizer in Minnesota and Ohio. And then I started grad school at UMass Amherst and later transferred to Berkeley.â After earning his PhD in 2004, he came directly to SIPA, where he received tenure in 2010. In a study of soccer ball manufacturers in Pakistan, Professors Eric Verhoogen of SIPA and Amit Khandelwal, Gary Winnick and Martin Granoff of Columbia Business School found that how workers are paid, and whether or not incentives are offered, can promote or stifle the adoption of a new technology. Below were some additional information Verhoogen shared about the study and some other things heâs working on. You found clearly that misaligned incentives can compromise the adoption of otherwise beneficial technology. Why is this significant, and what are the challenges inherent in a study like this? Itâs an interesting, important question for economic development and growth more generally. Itâs also a hard question to study because itâs hard to observe technology use by manufacturing firms and rare to have information about the actual cost and benefits of technology. This is partly because technologies vary a lot across firms, and particularly across sectors. And unlike other types of data, itâs hard to collect via surveyâ"sometimes firms donât want to share information. Economists have other methods to estimate productivity, but theyâre all pretty indirect. Why soccer balls? I realize itâs just a coincidence that weâre in the middle of the World Cup tournament. With soccer-ball producers [in Sialkot, Pakistan], you have a pretty large number of firms, 135, producing a standardized product using similar technology. So the same basic production process is used by large and small firms alike. We thought we could introduce a new technology that would be useful to these guys, to producers, and focus on the diffusion process. As the Columbia News story explains, Verhoogen and his team developed a fabric-cutting die that would enable producers to use fabric more efficiently, creating an opportunity to cut costs and increase profits. Is it unusual that your team of researchers gave the manufacturers a technological advancement? Does it impact the study somehow? In development economics, thereâs been a broad trend over 15 or 20 years, of having more of these experimental interventions. Thereâs a large literature on technology adoption in agriculture where researchers share information about improved production processes. Whatâs more unusual about our study is that we are focusing on larger manufacturing firms and especially that we invented the technology we gave out. So what happened when you introduced the new technology? We gave the dies out in May 2012, and to be honest we were expecting very fast adoption. We were planning to focus on the diffusion process, seeing how the technology spread to firms we didnât give it to. We had evidence to indicate that the technology was working, that it was more efficient, but after 15 months only six firms had adopted the new technology. This was a puzzlingly low adoption rate, so we decided to write a paper about that. The number-one reason firms didnât adopt the new technology was that the employees were unwilling to use it. What became clear was that the cutters actually cutting the material are paid a piece rate per pentagon or hexagon. They want to go as fast as possible and donât care about waste. Our new technology slowed them down initially, certainly for the first month or two, and given their wage contract they have no incentive to adopt new technology. So we formulated this hypothesis that the misalignment of incentives was a key constraint to adoption. We did a second experiment to probe thisâ"we explained the misalignment and said we would pay a lump-sum bonus of one monthâs salary, about $150, to the cutter if in one month he could demonstrate competence in the new technology. The incentive program led to a 26 percent increase in probability of adoption of the new treatment. That such a small incentive targeted at workers could have a significant effect indicated to us that the misalignment of incentives is why the technology wasnât being adopted. Can you elaborate on the significance of your findings, and the study? One piece of the big picture is that you have to have employee buy-in. Workers will only cooperate in the adoption of new technologies if they expect to gainâ"and if they donât cooperate, they can effectively block it. Also, by introducing the innovation we were able to actually observe the process and statistically distinguish between different hypotheses, as opposed to in case studies. This was a particularly clean setting, and we have a strong argument that the new technology is beneficial for essentially all firms. I think this sort of thing happens all the time in many different settings. We happened to be able to observe it in one setting, but we think there are many incremental changes that could be made in different settings, and make a big difference. Traditional economists sometimes say there canât be a $100 bill on the sidewalk because if there were, someone would pick it up. We think this is a $100 bill on the sidewalk, but firms arenât picking it up. Youâre also the director of SIPAâs Center for Development Economics and Policy. How has CDEP been received since it formally launched in November 2013? Thereâs a lot of enthusiasm about development economics at SIPA. Thereâs been a great response from students and faculty members, and also from people outside SIPA. We have a couple of initiatives that are gaining momentum. One is a human capital initiative for human education and health issuesâ"what leads someone to acquire education, what factors shape education and health, and what are the consequences of that for a labor market. Another is our firms and innovations initiative, which examines issues around industrial upgrading in developing countriesâ" the question of why some countries can grow and thrive in world economy and some less so. Another coincidence with the World Cup⦠youâre also pursuing research in Brazil. In Brazil, with support from the Presidentâs Global Innovation Fund, I have a project on the interaction between labor market regulation and innovation at the firm level. The question is, how do firms respond to labor market regulation? Economists tend to think of the effect of labor regulation as uniformly negative, but weâre investigating whether there are less familiar but important positive effects on firm behavior. For example, the minimum wage in Brazil has risen a lot. The minimum wage affects the relative cost of hiring different types of workers, more low-skill than high-skill. If you give firms incentive to upgrade the composition of their workforce that may in turn induce them to use higher quality inputs, to produce higher quality outputs for sale to richer people in Brazil or richer export markets. Youâve lived and worked in many different and interesting places. After almost 10 years here, how does SIPA measure up? I very much like being at SIPA and teaching SIPA students because it keeps me grounded in the world. Our students have experience in the world and theyâre planning to go back and be involved in things on the groundâ"I think itâs healthy and stimulating for me to be exposed to them and to be at a place that respects policy-oriented work. I got into this job to make the world a better place and I havenât given up hope that thatâs possible.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.